Redian新闻
>
法律翻译|美国反垄断法经典案例:国家石油公司诉可汗案

法律翻译|美国反垄断法经典案例:国家石油公司诉可汗案

社会

译者 | 孙书朋 西南政法大学 国际法学硕士

审稿 | 张庆 复旦大学法律硕士

   LYJ 新加坡国立大学LL.M.

编辑 | 李建云 湖南师范大学本科

责编 | 王有蓉 西安外国语大学本科


前言

本案是美国反垄断法领域的经典案例。该案分析了本身违法原则和合理原则这两个反垄断法领域最重要的原则之间的适用关系,即法院只有在积累大量经验并且有足够的信息确信有关行为就算采用合理原则裁判也会得出违法结论后,方可适用本身违法原则。通过该分析,法院最终得出结论:纵向最高价格维持本身并没有违反反垄断法,并且应该依据合理原则对该行为进行审查,从而推翻了Albrecht v. Herald Co.一案的判决。

State Oil Co. v. Khan
国家石油公司诉可汗案*


目录

Part1: Case Summary 案件概要

I.  Procedural Posture 案件审理历程

II.  Overview 概要

Part2: Opinion 判决理由

I.   第一部分

II.  第二部分

*注:译者翻译本判例时已省略原判决书中的注释

Case Summary

案件概要


I. Procedural Posture

案件审理历程


Petitioner oil company sought review of a decision from the United States Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit that reversed summary judgment for petitioner on respondents' claim under the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C.S. § 1. The appeals court held based on Supreme Court precedent that petitioner's vertical maximum price fixing scheme was a per se antitrust violation and respondents could have suffered injury from not being able to adjust prices.


上诉人石油公司要求对美国第七巡回上诉法院所作的裁定进行审查,该院撤销了针对被上诉人依据《谢尔曼法》所提出的诉讼请求而作出的简易判决(summary judgment)。上诉法院依据联邦最高法院的先例裁定上诉人的纵向最高价格维持方案[1]本身违反(per se violation)[2]反垄断法,并且被上诉人可能会因不能调整价格而遭受损害。


II. Overview

概要


The court of appeals reversed summary judgment in favor of petitioner oil company on respondent gas station operators' claim under the Sherman Act (Act), 15 U.S.C.S. § 1. The appeals court found it was bound to follow Supreme Court precedent and rule that petitioner's vertical maximum price fixing scheme was a per se antitrust violation and that respondents could have suffered injury from not being able to adjust gasoline prices. The court vacated the judgment and remanded the case for further proceedings. The court held that vertical maximum price fixing was not a per se violation of the Act, and that such price fixing arrangements should be evaluated under the rule of reason. According to the court, there was insufficient economic justification for per se invalidation of vertical maximum price fixing. The court overruled the precedent relied upon by the appeals court, Albrecht v. Herald Co., 390 U.S. 145, 19 L. Ed. 2d 998 (1968), which held that vertical maximum price fixing was per se unlawful. Despite the doctrine of stare decisis, Albrecht was overruled because its theoretical underpinnings had been called into serious question.


上诉法院撤销了针对被上诉人加油站运营方依据《谢尔曼法》所提出的请求而作出的简易判决,该判决裁定上诉人石油公司胜诉。上诉法院认为其应当遵循联邦最高法院的先例,并且据此裁定上诉人的纵向最高价格维持方案本身违反了反垄断法,并且被上诉人可能会因不能调整价格而遭受损害。美国联邦最高法院撤销了原判,并发回重审。联邦最高法院认为纵向最高价格维持本身并没有违反反垄断法,并且应当根据合理原则(rule of reason)[3]对该方案进行审查。联邦最高法院还认为,从经济角度看,并没有足够的理由认定纵向最高价格维持本身是无效的。联邦最高法院推翻了上诉法院所援引的先例(Albrecht v. Herald Co.),该先例认为纵向最高价格维持本身是不合法的。尽管存在遵循先例原则,但是Albrecht v. Herald Co.一案的判决依然被推翻了,其原因在于该判决的理论基础遭到了质疑。


Opinion

判决理由


JUSTICE O'CONNOR delivered the opinion of the Court.


本判决由奥康纳大法官作出。


Under § 1 of the Sherman Act, 26 Stat. 209, as amended, 15 U.S.C. § 1, "every contract, combination..., or conspiracy, in restraint of trade" is illegal. In Albrecht v. Herald Co., 390 U.S. 145, 19 L. Ed. 2d 998, 88 S. Ct. 869 (1968), this Court held that vertical maximum price fixing is a per se violation of that statute. In this case, we are asked to reconsider that decision in light of subsequent decisionsof this Court. We conclude that Albrecht should be overruled.


《谢尔曼法》第1条(《制定法大全》第26卷第209页)及其修正案(《美国法典》第15标题卷第1条)规定:“任何限制贸易的合同、合并以及共谋都是非法的。”在Albrecht v. Herald Co.案中,上诉法院认为纵向最高价格维持本身违反了该法的规定。在本案中,鉴于上诉法院后续所作出的判决,我们需要重新审议该案的裁决。最终,我们认为Albrecht 案的判决应当被推翻。



I.

第一部分


Respondents, Barkat U. Khan and his corporation, entered into an agreement with petitioner, State Oil Company, to lease and operate a gas station and convenience store owned by State Oil. The agreement provided that respondents would obtain the station's gasoline supply from State Oil at a price equal to a suggested retail price set by State Oil, less a margin of 3.25 cents per gallon. Under the agreement, respondents could charge any amount for gasoline sold to the station's customers, but if the price charged was higher than State Oil's suggested retail price, the excess was to be rebated to State Oil. Respondents could sell gasoline for less than State Oil's suggested retail price, but any such decrease would reduce their 3.25 cents-per-gallon margin.


被上诉人(巴拉卡特·U·可汗及其公司)与上诉人(国家石油公司)签订了一份协议,该协议约定将国家石油公司所有的便利店和加油站出租给被上诉人并由其运营。该协议还约定国家石油公司将按照其所设定的建议零售价(每加仑的利润低于3.25美分)向被上诉人的加油站供油。根据该协议,被上诉人可以以任意价格向客户出售汽油,但是如果该价格高于国家石油公司的建议零售价,那么超过部分将归国家石油公司所有。被上诉人可以以低于建议零售价的价格出售汽油,但是这会使得每加仑的利润减少3.25美分。


About a year after respondents began operating the gas station, they fell behind in lease payments. State Oil then gave notice of its intent to terminate the agreement and commenced a state court proceeding to evict respondents. At State Oil's request, the state court appointed a receiver to operate the gas station. The receiver operated the station for several months without being subject to the price restraints in respondents' agreement with State Oil. According to respondents, the receiver obtained an overall profit margin in excess of 3.25 cents per gallon by lowering the price of regular-grade gasoline and raising the price of premium grades.


在被上诉人运营加油站一年后,他们无法按时缴纳租金。于是,国家石油公司通知被上诉人其欲解除合同,并会向州法院提起诉讼以驱逐被上诉人。应国家石油公司的请求,州法院指定接管人(receiver)运营加油站。接管人不受被上诉人和国家石油公司约定的价格限制的约束,并在此情形下运营了加油站数月。被上诉人称,在降低一般等级汽油价格,并提高高级汽油价格后,接管人所获的总体利润超过每加仑3.25美分。


Respondents sued State Oil in the United States District Court for the Northern District of Illinois, alleging in part that State Oil had engaged in price fixing in violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act by preventing respondents from raising or lowering retail gas prices. According to the complaint, but for the agreement with State Oil, respondents could have charged different prices based on the grades of gasoline, in the same way that the receiver had, thereby achieving increased sales and profits. State Oil responded that the agreement did not actually prevent respondents from setting gasoline prices, and that, in substance, respondents did not allege a violation of antitrust laws by their claim that State Oil's suggested retail price was not optimal.


被上诉人在美国伊利诺伊州北区地区法院起诉国家石油公司,诉称国家石油公司通过禁止被上诉人提高或者降低零售汽油价格来实施转售价格维持,此举违反《谢尔曼法》第1条的规定。被上诉人还称,如果没有与国家石油公司签订协议,被上诉人本可以和接管人一样,根据汽油的等级收取不同的费用,以此提高销售额和利润。国家石油公司则辩称,该协议实际上并没有禁止被上诉人自行设定汽油价格,并且实质上,被上诉人不能因为国家石油公司的建议零售价格并非是最佳选择,而主张国家石油公司违反了反垄断法。


(图片来源于网络)


The District Court found that the allegations in the complaint did not state a per se violation of the Sherman Act because they did not establish the sort of "manifestly anticompetitive implications or pernicious effect on competition" that would justify per se prohibition of State Oil's conduct. App. 43-44. Subsequently, in ruling on cross-motions for summary judgment, the District Court concluded that respondents had failed to demonstrate antitrust injury or harm to competition.  App. to Pet. for Cert. 37a. The District Court held that respondents had not shown that a difference in gasoline pricing would have increased the station's sales; nor had they shown that State Oil had market power or that its pricing provisions affected competition in a relevant market. Id., at 37a, 40a. Accordingly, the District Court entered summary judgment for State Oil on respondents' Sherman Act claim. Id., at 40a.


地区法院审理后认为,由于被上诉人诉状中的主张并没有证明国家石油公司具有“明显的反竞争意图或者对竞争具有破坏性影响”,而这一证据能为禁止国家石油公司实施转售价格维持本身提供正当理由,因此被上诉人诉状中的主张并不能说明国家石油公司行为本身违反了《谢尔曼法》。随后,地区法院在裁定有关简易判决的反制动议时,得出结论:被上诉人未能说明反垄断法损害[4]或者对竞争的损害。地区法院认为,被上诉人并没有说明不同的汽油价格会提高加油站的销售额。此外,被上诉人也未能说明国家石油公司拥有市场支配力或者其定价规定影响了相关市场的竞争。据此,地区法院针对被上诉人根据《谢尔曼法》提出的诉讼请求作出了国家石油公司胜诉的简易判决。


The Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit reversed.  93 F.3d 1358 (1996). The court first noted that the agreement between respondents and State Oil did indeed fix maximum gasoline prices by making it "worthless" for respondents to exceed the suggested retail prices.  Id., at 1360. After reviewing legal and economic aspects of price fixing, the court concluded that State Oil's pricing scheme was a per se antitrust violation under Albrecht v. Herald Co., supra. Although the Court of Appeals characterized Albrecht as "unsound when decided" and "inconsistent with later decisions" of this Court, it felt constrained to follow that decision.  93 F.3d at 1363. In light of Albrecht and Atlantic Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328, 109 L. Ed. 2d 333, 110 S. Ct. 1884 (1990) (ARCO), the court found that respondents could have suffered antitrust injury from not being able to adjust gasoline prices.


第七巡回上诉法院撤销了上述判决。首先,上诉法院注意到被上诉人和国家石油公司之间的协议使得被上诉人无法获得超过建议零售价的部分利润,从而固定了汽油的最高售价。上诉法院从法律和经济层面考察了固定最高售价的后果之后,最终依据Albrecht v. Herald Co.这一先例认为国家石油公司的价格机制本身违反了反垄断法。尽管上诉法院认为Albrecht案在判决时并非完美无缺,并且与上诉法院之后的判决也不一致,但是上诉法院依然遵循了这一先例。考虑到Albrecht案和Atlantic Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co.案的判决,上诉法院裁定被上诉人因无法调整汽油价格而遭受了反垄断损害。

We granted certiorari to consider two questions, whether State Oil's conduct constitutes a per se violation of the Sherman Act and whether respondents are entitled to recover damages based on that conduct. 519 U.S.     (1997).


我们签发了调卷令(certiorari),以查明以下两个问题,即国家石油公司的行为本身是否违反了《谢尔曼法》,以及被上诉人是否有权依据国家石油公司的这一行为要求获得损害赔偿。



II.

第二部分


A


Although the Sherman Act, by its terms, prohibits every agreement "in restraint of trade," this Court has long recognized that Congress intended to outlaw only unreasonable restraints. See, e.g., Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Soc., 457 U.S. 332, 342-343, 73 L. Ed. 2d 48, 102 S. Ct. 2466 (1982) (citing United States v. Joint Traffic Assn., 171 U.S. 505, 43 L. Ed. 259, 19 S. Ct. 25 (1898)). As a consequence, most antitrust claims are analyzed under a "rule of reason,"  according to which the finder of fact must decide whether the questioned practice imposes an unreasonable restraint on competition, taking into account a variety of factors, including specific information about the relevant business, its condition before and after the restraint was imposed, and the restraint's history, nature, and effect.  457 U.S. at 343, and n. 13 (citing Board of Trade of Chicago v. United States, 246 U.S. 231, 238, 62 L. Ed. 683, 38 S. Ct. 242 (1918)).


尽管《谢尔曼法》禁止任何“限制贸易”(in restraint of trade)的协议,但是上诉法院一直以来都认为国会的本意只是想禁止不合理的限制。因此,上诉法院是依据“合理原则”来分析绝大部分和反垄断法有关的诉讼请求。这一原则要求事实裁定者必须在综合考虑多种因素(包括有关行业的特定信息、某种限制产生前后该行业所处的状态以及该种限制的历史、性质和影响)后判定被诉行为是否对竞争产生了不合理的限制。


(图片来源于网络)


Some types of restraints, however, have such predictable and pernicious anticompetitive effect, and such limited potential for procompetitive benefit, that they are deemed unlawful per se.  Northern Pacific R. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 5, 2 L. Ed. 2d 545, 78 S. Ct. 514 (1958).Per se treatment is appropriate "once experience with a particular kind of restraint enables the Court to predict with confidence that the rule of reason will condemn it." Maricopa County, supra, at 344; see also Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc., 441 U.S. 1, 19, n. 33, 60 L. Ed. 2d 1, 99 S. Ct. 1551 (1979). Thus, we have expressed reluctance to adopt per se rules with regard to "restraints imposed in the context of business relationships where the economic impact of certain practices is not immediately obvious." FTC v. Indiana Federation of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 458-459, 90 L. Ed. 2d 445, 106 S. Ct. 2009 (1986).

但是,有些类型的限制会对竞争产生破坏性的影响,并且不太可能产生促进竞争的效果,因而这些限制本身(per se)被认为是不合法的。“只有当法院对某种类型的限制的审判经验使之有把握预测合理原则会证明该种限制是不合法时”,运用本身违法原则(per se rule)才是适当的。[5]因此,“当对商业关系所施加的限制对经济的影响不能够立刻显现的时候”,我们不会采用本身违法原则。


A review of this Court's decisions leading up to and beyond Albrecht is relevant to our assessment of the continuing validity of the per se rule established in Albrecht. Beginning with Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373, 55 L. Ed. 502, 31 S. Ct. 376 (1911), the Court recognized the illegality of agreements under which manufacturers or suppliers set the minimum resale prices to be charged by their distributors. By 1940, the Court broadly declared all business combinations "formed for the purpose and with the effect of raising, depressing, fixing, pegging, or stabilizing the price of a commodity in interstate or foreign commerce" illegal per se.  United States v. Socony-Vacuum  Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150, 223, 84 L. Ed. 1129, 60 S. Ct. 811 (1940). Accordingly, the Court condemned an agreement between two affiliated liquor distillers to limit the maximum price charged by retailers in Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, Inc., 340 U.S. 211, 95 L. Ed. 219, 71 S. Ct. 259 (1951), noting that agreements to fix maximum prices, "no less than those to fix minimum prices, cripple the freedom of traders and thereby restrain their ability to sell in accordance with their own judgment." Id., at 213.


审查上诉法院在Albrecht案发生前后所做的判决与评估该案中所确立的本身违法原则的后续有效性密切相关。从Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co.案开始,上诉法院就意识到生产商或者供应商为批发商设置最低转售价格(minimum resale prices)[6]的协议是非法的。在1940年之前,上诉法院就大体上宣布所有“在州际贸易或者对外贸易过程中以提高、抑制、固定或者稳定某种商品的价格为目的以及会产生此类后果的”企业合并本身都是非法的。因此,上诉法院在Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, Inc.案中,就认为固定最高转售价格协议,“和固定最低转售价格协议一样会削弱零售商的自由,从而限制其根据自己的判断出售商品的能力,故宣判两家白酒蒸馏分支企业之间签订的此类协议是非法的”。


In subsequent cases, the Court's attention turned to arrangements through which suppliers imposed restrictions on dealers with respect to matters other than resale price. In White Motor Co. v. United States, 372 U.S. 253, 9 L. Ed. 2d 738, 83 S. Ct. 696 (1963), the Court considered the validity of a manufacturer's assignment of exclusive territories to its distributors and dealers. The Court determined that too little was known about the competitive impact of such vertical limitations to warrant treating them as per se unlawful.  Id., at 263. Four years later, in United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365, 18 L. Ed. 2d 1249, 87 S. Ct. 1856 (1967), the Court reconsidered the status of exclusive dealer territories and held that, upon the transfer of title to goods to a distributor, a supplier's imposition of territorial restrictions on the distributor was "so obviously destructive of competition" as to constitute a per se violation of the Sherman Act. Id., at 379. In Schwinn, the Court acknowledged that some vertical restrictions, such as the conferral of territorial rights or franchises, could have procompetitive benefits by allowing smaller enterprises to compete, and that such restrictions might avert vertical integration in the distribution process.  Id., at 379-380. The Court drew the line, however, at permitting manufacturers to control product marketing once dominion over the goods had passed to dealers. Id., at 380.


在后续案件中,上诉法院开始关注供应商之间限制除价格以外其他事项的安排。在White Motor Co. v. United States一案中,上诉法院考虑了生产商在各批发商和经销商之间分配排他性经销商区域(exclusive dealer territories)的合法性。由于上诉法院无从知晓此类纵向限制对竞争产生的影响,因而无法认定该限制是非法的。四年后,在United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co.案中,上诉法院重新审议了排他性经销商区域的法律地位,并认为一旦货物所有权转移给批发商后,供应商对批发商销售区域的限制“明显破坏了市场竞争”,因此该行为本身违反了《谢尔曼法》。在Schwinn案中,上诉法院承认诸如授予排他性经营权或者特许经营权等纵向限制使得规模较小的企业也能参与市场竞争,从而促进了市场竞争,并且此类限制可以避免在分销过程中产生纵向一体化(vertical integration)[7]。但是,上诉法院在一定范围内允许生产商在将货物所有权转移给经销商后,控制产品的市场营销。

Albrecht, decided the following Term, involved a newspaper publisher who had granted exclusive territories to independent carriers subject to their adherence to a maximum price on resale of the newspapers to the public. Influenced by its decisions in Socony-Vacuum, Kiefer-Stewart, and Schwinn, the Court concluded that it was per se unlawful for the publisher to fix the maximum resale price of its newspapers. 390 U.S. at 152-154. The Court acknowledged that "maximum and minimum price fixing  may have different consequences in many situations," but nonetheless condemned maximum price fixing for "substituting the perhaps erroneous judgment of a seller for the forces of the competitive market." Id., at 152.

Albrecht一案涉及一家报纸出版商将排他性经营区授予给独立的运输公司,但条件是这些运输公司需要遵守出版商设置的最高转售价,该案决定了后续案件的判决。在该案判决的影响下,上诉法院在Socony-Vacuum案, Kiefer-Stewart案, 以及Schwinn案中均认为出版商设置报纸最高转售价的行为本身是不合法的。上诉法院虽然承认“在很多情况下,维持最高和最低价格会产生不同的后果”,但是由于维持最高价格“会代替卖方对竞争市场的力量作出的潜在的误判,因而此类行为仍然是不合法的”。


Albrecht was animated in part by the fear that vertical maximum price fixing could allow suppliers to discriminate against certain dealers, restrict the services that dealers could afford to offer customers, or disguise minimum price fixing schemes.  Id., at 152-153. The Court rejected the notion (both on the record of that case and in the abstract) that, because the newspaper publisher "granted exclusive territories, a price ceiling was necessary to protect the public from price gouging by dealers who had monopoly power in their own territories." Id., at 153.
 

Albrecht案之所以会有如此大的影响力,部分原因在于人们担心纵向最高价格维持会让供应商歧视特定的分销商,限制经销商可以提供给顾客的服务,或者会掩饰最低价格维持(minimum price fixing)。上诉法院在案件卷宗和摘要中都否认了这样一种观点,即由于报纸出版商“授予排他性经营区,所以需要设置最高价格来防止分销商在自己的排他性经营区内滥用专营权抬高价格”。


(图片来源于网络)


In a vigorous dissent, Justice Harlan asserted that the majority had erred in equating the effects of maximum and minimum price fixing. Id., at 156-168 (Harlan, J., dissenting). Justice Harlan pointed out that, because the majority was establishing a per se rule, the proper inquiry was "not whether dictation of maximum prices is ever illegal, but whether it is always illegal." Id., at 165-166. He also faulted the majority for conclusively listing "certain unfortunate consequences that maximum price dictation might have in other cases," even as it rejected evidence that the publisher's practice of fixing maximum prices counteracted potentially anticompetitive actions by its distributors. Id., at 165. Justice Stewart also dissented, asserting that the publisher's maximum price fixing scheme should be properly viewed as promoting competition, because it protected consumers from dealers such as Albrecht, who, as "the only person who could sell for home delivery the city's only daily morning newspaper," was "a monopolist within his own territory." Id., at 168 (Stewart, J., dissenting).

哈伦大法官对上述观点表示强烈反对。他认为多数意见错误地将最高价格维持的影响等同于最低价格维持的影响。哈伦大法官指出,由于多数意见确立了本身违法原则,因此他们不应该去探究“指定最高价格的行为以往是否是非法的,而是要探究这种行为是否一直都是非法的”。他还批评多数意见确切地列出了“指定最高价格在其他情况下可能产生的负面结果”,却否认了出版商维持最高价格的行为会抵消批发商潜在的反竞争行为这一事实。斯图尔特大法官也同样表示反对。他认为只有Albrecht之类的经销商可以为每户家庭配送城市中仅有的晨报,故他们是其排他性经营区内的垄断者,而出版商维持最高价格的行为却能保护当地的消费者,因而此类行为应当被认为是促进了竞争。

Nine years later, in Continental T. V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 53 L. Ed. 2d 568, 97 S. Ct. 2549 (1977), the Court overruled Schwinn, thereby rejecting application of a per se rule in the context of vertical nonprice restrictions. The Court acknowledged the principle of stare decisis, but explained that the need for clarification in the law justified reconsideration of Schwinn: "Since its announcement, Schwinn has been the subject of continuing controversy and confusion, both in the scholarly journals and in the federal courts. The great weight of scholarly opinion has been critical of the decision, and a number of the federal courts confronted with analogous vertical restrictions have sought to limit its reach. In our view, the experience of the past 10 years should be brought to bear on this subject of considerable commercial importance." 433 U.S. at 47-49 (footnotes omitted).


九年之后,上诉法院在Continental T. V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc.一案中推翻了Schwinn案的判决,因此未在非价格纵向限制的情形下运用本身违法原则。尽管上诉法院认同遵循先例原则,但是上诉法院认为为了阐明法律,应该重新审议Schwinn一案的判决:“自从Schwinn案宣判后,其一直都是学术期刊和联邦法院争论的焦点,同时也引起了大家的困惑。大量的学者批评了该案的判决,并且很多联邦法院在审理类似纵向限制的案件时都努力限制该判决的适用。在我们看来,过去十年的经验应当能为这一具有重大商业意义的问题带来新的视角。”


The Court considered the historical context of Schwinn, noting that Schwinn's per se rule against vertical nonprice restrictions came only four years after the Court had refused to endorse a similar rule in White Motor Co., and that the decision neither explained the "sudden change in position," nor referred to the accepted requirements for per se violations set forth in Northern Pacific R. Co., 433 U.S. at 51-52. The Court then reviewed scholarly works supporting the economic utility of vertical nonprice restraints. See id., at 54-57 (citing, e.g., Posner, Antitrust Policy and the Supreme Court: An Analysis of the Restricted Distribution, Horizontal Merger and Potential Competition Decisions, 75 Colum. L. Rev. 282 (1975); Preston, Restrictive Distribution Arrangements: Economic Analysis and Public Policy Standards, 30 Law & Contemp. Prob. 506 (1965)). The Court concluded that, because "departure from the rule-of-reason standard must be based upon demonstrable economic effect rather than--as in Schwinn --upon formalistic line drawing," the appropriate course would be "to return to the rule of reason that governed vertical restrictions prior to Schwinn." GTE Sylvania, supra, at 58-59.


上诉法院考虑了Schwinn案的历史背景,并注意到在上诉法院拒绝将类似原则适用于White Motor Co.案四年后,Schwinn案就适用了本身违法原则认定非价格纵向限制是违法的。此外,上诉法院还注意到Schwinn案的判决既未解释“地位的突然改变”一词的含义,也未指向Northern Pacific R. Co.案中所确定的本身违法原则的构成要件。之后,上诉法院又阅读了一些证实了非价格纵向限制的经济效用的学术著作。最终,上诉法院得出结论:“要想逾越合理原则就必须论证某种行为对经济产生的影响,而不是像Schwinn案一样只在形式上划清界限”,因此“回归到在Schwinn案之前也一直适用于纵向限制的合理原则”才是合适的。


In GTE Sylvania, the Court declined to comment on Albrecht's per se treatment of vertical maximum price restrictions, noting that the issue "involved significantly different questions of analysis and policy." 433 U.S. at 51, n. 18. Subsequent decisions of the Court, however, have hinted that the analytical underpinnings of Albrecht were substantially weakened by GTE Sylvania. We noted in Maricopa County that vertical restraints are generally more defensible than horizontal restraints. See 457 U.S. at 348, n. 18. And we explained in 324 Liquor Corp. v. Duffy, 479 U.S. 335, 341-342, 93 L. Ed. 2d 667, 107 S. Ct. 720 (1987), that decisions such as GTE Sylvania "recognize the possibility that a vertical restraint imposed by a single manufacturer or wholesaler may stimulate interbrand competition even as it reduces intrabrand competition."

在GTE Sylvania案中,上诉法院拒绝就Albrecht一案将本身违法原则适用于纵向最高价格限制作出评论,并注意到这一问题“涉及到不同的分析与政策问题”。但是,在上诉法院后续判决中,我们发现GTE Sylvania案严重削弱了Albrecht案的分析基础。我们在Maricopa County 案中注意到纵向限制相较于横向限制通常更合乎情理,并且我们在Liquor Corp v. Duffy案中指出,诸如GTE Sylvania案一类的判决“承认了这样一种可能性,即尽管单一的生产商或者批发商所实施的纵向限制会降低品牌内的竞争(interbrand competition),但是却可以促进品牌间的竞争(intrabrand competition)”。[8]


Most recently, in ARCO, 495 U.S. 328, 110 S. Ct. 1884, 109 L. Ed. 2d 333 (1990), although Albrecht's continuing validity was not squarely before the Court, some disfavor with that decision was signaled by our statement that we would "assume, arguendo, that Albrecht correctly held that vertical, maximum price fixing is subject to the per se rule." 495 U.S. at 335, n. 5. More significantly, we specifically acknowledged that vertical maximum price fixing "may have procompetitive interbrand effects," and pointed out that, in the wake of GTE Sylvania, "the procompetitive potential of a vertical maximum price restraint is more evident...than it was when Albrecht was decided, because exclusive territorial arrangements and other nonprice restrictions were unlawful per se in 1968." 495 U.S. at 343, n. 13 (citing several commentators identifying procompetitive effects of vertical maximum price fixing, including, e.g., P. Areeda & H. Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law P340.30b, p. 378, n. 24 (1988 Supp.); Blair & Harrison, Rethinking Antitrust Injury, 42 Vand. L. Rev. 1539, 1553 (1989); Easterbrook, Maximum Price Fixing, 48 U. Chi. L. Rev. 886, 887-890 (1981)).

在最近的ARCO案中,尽管Albrecht案的持续有效性并非是上诉法院的审理范围,但是我们假定Albrecht案将本身违法原则适用于纵向最高价格维持是正确的,以此表达了我们对该判决些许的反对。更重要地是,我们明确承认纵向价格维持可以促进品牌间的竞争,并且指出随着 GTE Sylvania案的宣判,“纵向最高价格限制可能产生的促进竞争的效果较Albrecht案宣判时更加明显......这是因为在1968年的时候,排他性经营区安排和其他非价格限制本身是非法的”。


(图片来源于网络)



B


Thus, our reconsideration of Albrecht's continuing validity is informed by several of our decisions, as well as a considerable body of scholarship discussing the effects of vertical restraints. Our analysis is also guided by our general view that the primary purpose of the antitrust laws is to protect interbrand competition. See, e.g., Business Electronics Corp. v. Sharp Electronics Corp., 485 U.S. 717, 726, 99 L. Ed. 2d 808, 108 S. Ct. 1515 (1988). "Low prices," we have explained, "benefit consumers regardless of how those prices are set, and so long as they are above predatory levels, they do not threaten competition." ARCO, supra, at 340. Our interpretation of the Sherman Act also incorporates the notion that condemnation of practices resulting in lower prices to consumers is "especially costly" because "cutting prices in order to increase business often is the very essence of competition." Matsushita Elec. Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 594, 89 L. Ed. 2d 538, 106 S. Ct. 1348 (1986).

因此,我们对Albrecht案持续有效性的重新审议,是基于我们的几份判决以及大量的关于纵向限制所产生的影响的学术讨论。我们的分析是在这样一个一般性观点的指引下展开的,即反垄断法的主要目的在于保护品牌间的竞争。正如我们所解释的那样,“无论如何设置低价,它们都会给消费者带来好处,并且只要低价没有达到掠夺性的程度,那么低价就不会对竞争产生威胁”。在解释《谢尔曼法》的时候,我们也认为“为了扩大业务而降价是竞争的本质”,因此认定导致降价的行为是非法的会付出“惨痛代价”。


So informed, we find it difficult to maintain that vertically-imposed maximum prices could harm consumers or competition to the extent necessary to justify their per se invalidation. As Chief Judge Posner wrote for the Court of Appeals in this case:


正因如此,我们很难认定纵向最高价格维持对消费者或者竞争伤害之大以至于其本身就是不合法的。正如上诉法院首席法官波斯纳在本案判决书中所写的那样:


"As for maximum resale price fixing, unless the supplier is a monopsonist he cannot squeeze his dealers' margins below a competitive level; the attempt to do so would just drive the dealers into the arms of a competing supplier. A supplier might, however, fix a maximum resale price in order to prevent his dealers from exploiting a monopoly position...Suppose that State Oil, perhaps to encourage...dealer services...has spaced its dealers sufficiently far apart to limit competition among them (or even given each of them an exclusive territory); and suppose further that Union 76 is a sufficiently distinctive and popular brand to give the dealers in it at least a modicum of monopoly power. Then State Oil might want to place a ceiling on the dealers' resale prices in order to prevent them from exploiting that monopoly power fully. It would do this not out of disinterested malice, but in its commercial self-interest. The higher the price at which gasoline is resold, the smaller the volume sold, and so the lower the profit to the supplier if the higher profit per gallon at the higher price is being snared by the dealer." 93 F.3d at 1362. See also R. Bork, The Antitrust Paradox 281-282 (1978) ("There could, of course, be no anticonsumer effect from [the type of price fixing considered in Albrecht], and one suspects that the paper has a legitimate interest in keeping subscriber prices down in order to increase circulation and maximize revenues from advertising").


“至于最高转售价格维持,除非供应商是垄断者,否则他不会让分销商的利润毫无竞争力;如果他这么做了,那么只会让分销商投入竞争对手的怀抱。但是,为了防止分销商滥用垄断地位,供应商可能会固定最高转售价格......假设国家石油公司可能为了鼓励......分销商的服务......而将各分销商分隔开来以限制他们之间的竞争(或者授予每个分销商排他性经营区);以及进一步假设Union 76是一个非常著名和受欢迎的品牌,可以让分销商在其排他性经营区内获得一些垄断地位,那么国家石油公司可能想为分销商设置最高转售价以此阻止分销商充分利用垄断地位。国家石油公司之所以会这么做并非出于无私,而是为了自身的商业利益。汽油转售价越高,销售量越小,因此如果分销商获得了每加仑更多的利润,那么供应商获得的利润也就越低。”


We recognize that the Albrecht decision presented a number of theoretical justifications for a per se rule against vertical maximum price fixing. But criticism of those premises abounds. The Albrecht decision was grounded in the fear that maximum price fixing by suppliers could interfere with dealer freedom.  390 U.S. at 152. In response, as one commentator has pointed out, "the ban on maximum resale price limitations declared in Albrecht in the name of 'dealer freedom' has actually prompted many suppliers to integrate forward into distribution, thus eliminating the very independent trader for whom Albrecht professed solicitude." 7 P. Areeda, Antitrust Law, P1635, p. 395 (1989). For example, integration in the newspaper industry since Albrecht has given rise to litigation between independent distributors and publishers. See P. Areeda & H. Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law P729.7, pp. 599-614 (1996 Supp.).

我们意识到Albrecht案的判决运用了大量的理论来证明本身违法原则可以适用于纵向最高价格维持。但是,很多人批评了那些前提。Albrecht案的判决建立在这样一种担忧之上,即供应商实施最高价格维持会干涉分销商的自由。为了回应这一担忧,评论员指出:“Albrecht案以保护“经销商的自由”的名义禁止最高转售价格维持,这实际上促使很多供应商整合分销,恰恰让该案宣称所要保护的独立交易商在市场上难以立足。”例如,Albrecht案宣判后,报纸业就进行了整合,这引发了独立批发商和出版商之间的诉讼纠纷。


The Albrecht Court also expressed the concern that maximum prices may be set too low for dealers to offer consumers essential or desired services.  390 U.S. at 152-153. But such conduct, by driving away customers, would seem likely to harm manufacturers as well as dealers and consumers, making it unlikely that a supplier would set such a price as a matter of business judgment. See, e.g., Lopatka, Stephen Breyer and Modern Antitrust: A Snug Fit, 40 Antitrust Bull. 1, 60 (1995); Blair & Lang, Albrecht After ARCO: Maximum Resale Price Fixing Moves Toward the Rule of Reason, 44 Vand. L. Rev. 1007, 1034 (1991). In addition, Albrecht noted that vertical maximum price fixing could effectively channel distribution through large or specially-advantaged dealers. 390 U.S. at 153. It is unclear, however, that a supplier would profit from limiting its market by excluding potential dealers. See, e.g., Easterbrook, supra, at 905-908. Further, although vertical maximum price fixing might limit the viability of inefficient dealers, that consequence is not necessarily harmful to competition and consumers. See, e.g., Easterbrook, supra, at 907; Lopatka, supra, at 60.

Albrecht案的审理法院也担心最高价格可能设置得太低了,使得分销商无法向消费者提供必要的或者所需的服务。但是,此类行为会使得顾客不再愿意购买他们的产品,进而可能伤害生产商、经销商和消费者的利益,这也会让供应商无法根据商业判断来设置此类价格。其次,Albrecht案指出,纵向价格维持可以有效地利用大型的或者有特别优势的分销商进行产品分销。但是,尚不清楚供应商是否能通过排除潜在的分销商来限制他的市场从而获利。再者,尽管纵向价格维持可能会限制效率低下的经销商的生存能力,但是这产生的后果未必会损害竞争和消费者的利益。

Finally, Albrecht reflected the Court's fear that maximum price fixing could be used to disguise arrangements to fix minimum prices, 390 U.S. at 153, which remain illegal per se. Although we have acknowledged the possibility that maximum pricing might mask minimum pricing, see Maricopa County, 457 U.S. at 348, we believe that such conduct -- as with the other concerns articulated in Albrecht -- can be appropriately recognized and punished under the rule of reason. See, e.g., Easterbrook, 48 U. Chi. L. Rev., at 901-904; see also Pitofsky, In Defense of Discounters: The No-Frills Case for a Per Se Rule Against Vertical Price Fixing, 71 Geo. L. J. 1487, 1490, n. 17 (1983).

最后,Albrecht案表明法院担心最高价格维持会被用来掩饰最低价格维持,而最低价格维持本身是不合法的。尽管我们承认最高价格维持可能掩饰最低价格维持,但是我们认为这一行为和Albrecht案中的其他问题一样可以被正确识别,并且根据合理原则予以惩罚。

Not only are the potential injuries cited in Albrecht less serious than the Court imagined, the per se rule established therein could in fact exacerbate problems related to the unrestrained exercise of market power by monopolist-dealers. Indeed, both courts and antitrust scholars have noted that Albrecht's rule may actually harm consumers and manufacturers. See, e.g., Caribe BMW, Inc. v. Bayerische Motoren Werke Aktiengesellschaft, 19 F.3d 745, 753 (CA1 1994) (Breyer, C. J.); Areeda, supra, P1636a, at 395; G. Mathewson & R. Winter, Competition Policy and Vertical Exchange 13-14 (1985). Other commentators have also explained that Albrecht's per se rule has even more potential for deleterious effect on competition after our decision in GTE Sylvania, because, now that vertical nonprice restrictions are not unlawful per se, the likelihood of dealer monopoly power is increased. See, e.g., Easterbrook, supra, at 890, n. 20; see also ARCO, 495 U.S.  at 343, n. 13. We do not intend to suggest that dealers generally possess sufficient market power to exploit a monopoly situation. Such retail market power may in fact be uncommon. See, e.g., Business Electronics, 485 U.S. at 727, n. 2; GTE Sylvania, 433 U.S. at 54. Nor do we hold that a ban on vertical maximum price fixing inevitably has anticompetitive consequences in the exclusive dealer context.

不仅Albrecht案中所指明的潜在伤害比法院所想象的要轻,而且该案所确立的本身违法原则事实上会加剧垄断分销商不受限制地行使市场支配力。其实,法院和反垄断学者都指出Albrecht案的裁决才会伤害消费者和生产商。其他评论员也认为在我们对GTE Sylvania案作出裁决后,Albrecht案中的本身违法原则更有可能损害竞争,这是因为既然非价格纵向限制本身是非法的,那么经销商更有可能行使垄断权力。但是,我们并不是认为经销商通常拥有足够的市场支配力去利用垄断地位。事实上,该零售市场支配力可能并不常见。同时,我们也不认为在排他性经销商存在的情况下,禁止纵向最高价格维持一定会产生反竞争的效果。

After reconsidering Albrecht's rationale and the substantial criticism the decision has received, however, we conclude that there is insufficient economic justification for per se invalidation of vertical maximum price fixing. That is so not only because it is difficult to accept the assumptions underlying Albrecht, but also because Albrecht has little or no relevance to ongoing enforcement of the Sherman Act. See Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 777, 81 L. Ed. 2d 628, 104 S. Ct. 2731, and n. 25 (1984).Moreover, neither the parties nor any of the amici curiae have called our attention to any cases in which enforcement efforts have been directed solely against the conduct encompassed by Albrecht's per se rule.

但是,在重新审议Albrecht案的判决逻辑和其受到的大量的批评后,我们最终认为从经济角度看,没有足够的理由认定纵向最高价格维持本身是违法的。这不仅是因为Albrecht案的底层假定很难让人接受,同时也是因为Albrecht案和《谢尔曼法》今后的执行并无联系。再者,原被告双方和法庭之友均未要求我们关注只针对适用Albrecht案本身违法原则的行为的执法活动。

Respondents argue that reconsideration of Albrecht should require "persuasive, expert testimony establishing that the per se rule has distorted the market." Brief for Respondents 7. Their reasoning ignores the fact that Albrecht itself relied solely upon hypothetical effects of vertical maximum price fixing. Further, Albrecht's dire predictions have not been borne out, even though manufacturers and suppliers appear to have fashioned schemes to get around the per se rule against vertical maximum price fixing. In these circumstances, it is the retention of the rule of Albrecht, and not, as respondents would have it, the rule's elimination, that lacks adequate justification. See, e.g., GTE Sylvania, supra, at 58-59.

被上诉人认为要想重新审议Albrecht案的判决,必须通过“具有说服力的专家证言来证明本身违法原则扭曲了市场”。但是,被上诉人的推理忽略了这样一个事实,即Albrecht案的判决本身只依靠猜想纵向最高价格维持所产生的影响。进一步讲,尽管生产商和供应商似乎已经找到了方案来规避本身违法原则对纵向价格维持的否认,但是Albrecht案所设想的可怕后果并没有应验。在此情况下,我们不该保留Albrecht案的判决,而应该像被上诉人所希望的那样,推翻该案的裁决。

Respondents' reliance on Toolson v. New York Yankees, Inc., 346 U.S. 356, 98 L. Ed. 64, 74 S. Ct. 78 (1953) (per curiam), and Flood v. Kuhn, 407 U.S. 258, 32 L. Ed. 2d 728, 92 S. Ct. 2099 (1972), is similarly misplaced, because those decisions are clearly inapposite, having to do with the antitrust exemption for professional baseball, which this Court has described as "an aberration...resting on a recognition and an acceptance of baseball's unique characteristics and needs," id., at 282. In the context of this case, we infer little meaning from the fact that Congress has not reacted legislatively to Albrecht. In any event, the history of various legislative proposals regarding price fixing seems neither clearly to support nor to denounce the per se rule of Albrecht. Respondents are of course free to seek legislative protection from gasoline suppliers of the sort embodied in the Petroleum Marketing Practices Act, 92 Stat. 322, 15 U.S.C. § 2801 et seq.. For the reasons we have noted, however, the remedy for respondents' dispute with State Oil should not come in the form of a per se rule affecting the conduct of the entire marketplace.

被上诉人还援引了Toolson v. New York Yankees, Inc.案和Flood v. Kuhn案的判决,但是这同样是不合理的,原因在于这两个案件的判决明显不当。法院认为前述案件给予专业棒球运动员反垄断豁免是“一种基于棒球运动员的特性和特殊需求的偏差”。在本案中,我们认为国会未根据Albrecht案进行立法这一事实对案件裁判没有意义。在任何情况下,和价格维持有关的不同立法提案的历史资料既不能支持也不能废除Albrecht案中的本身违法原则。当然,被上诉人有权向《石油销售行为法》(Petroleum Marketing Practices Act)中规定的汽油供应商寻求法律保护。但是,由于我们所知的原因,我们不能通过适用会影响整个市场行为的本身违法原则来解决被上诉人和国家石油公司的纠纷。


(图片来源于网络)



C

 
Despite what Chief Judge Posner aptly described as Albrecht's  "infirmities, [and] its increasingly wobbly, moth-eaten foundations," 93 F.3d at 1363, there remains the question whether Albrecht deserves continuing respect under the doctrine of stare decisis. The Court of Appeals was correct in applying that principle despite disagreement with Albrecht, for it is this Court's prerogative alone to overrule one of its precedents.

尽管首席法官波斯纳指出Albrecht案“已经显得不可靠,并且它的论证基础也变得越来越不稳定和过时,但是根据遵循先例原则Albrecht案的判决能否继续被援引仍然是个问题。尽管上诉法院并不认同Albrecht案的判决,但是其适用该案中确立的原则是正确的,因为上诉法院有权决定其是否推翻自己的先例。

We approach the reconsideration of decisions of this Court with the utmost caution. Stare decisis reflects "a policy judgment that 'in most matters it is more important that the applicable rule of law be settled than that it be settled right.'" Agostini v. Felton, 1997 U.S. LEXIS 4000, *58, 117 S. Ct. 1997, 138 L. Ed. 2d 391 (1997) (quoting Burnet v. Coronado Oil & Gas Co., 285 U.S. 393, 406, 76 L. Ed. 815, 52 S. Ct. 443 (1932) (Brandeis, J., dissenting)). It "is the preferred course because it promotes the evenhanded, predictable, and consistent development of legal principles, fosters reliance on judicial decisions, and contributes to the actual and perceived integrity of the judicial process." Payne v. Tennessee, 501 U.S. 808, 827, 115 L. Ed. 2d 720, 111 S. Ct. 2597 (1991). This Court has expressed its reluctance to overrule decisions involving statutory interpretation, see, e.g., Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.S. 720, 736, 52 L. Ed. 2d 707, 97 S. Ct. 2061 (1977), and has acknowledged that stare decisis concerns are at their acme in cases involving property and contract rights, see, e.g., Payne, 501 U.S. at 828. Both of those concerns are arguably relevant in this case.

我们谨慎地对上诉法院的判决进行了重新审议。遵循先例原则反映了“一种政策判断,即在绝大部分事项上,确立合适的法律原则要比确立正确的法律原则更重要”。“这是一种更受认可的习惯,因为它促进了法律原则发展的公平性、可预测性和一致性,对司法判决的依赖性以及公正司法程序的真实性和可被感知性“。上诉法院不愿意推翻涉及成文法解释的判决,并且认为在涉及财产权和合同权利的案件中,他们最关心的是遵循先例原则。毫无疑问,这两个问题和本案密切相关。

But "stare decisis is not an inexorable command." Ibid. In the area of antitrust law, there is a competing interest, well-represented in this Court's decisions, in recognizing and adapting to changed circumstances and the lessons of accumulated experience. Thus, the general presumption that legislative changes should be left to Congress has less force with respect to the Sherman Act in light of the accepted view that Congress "expected the courts to give shape to the statute's broad mandate by drawing on common-law tradition." National Soc. of Professional Engineers v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 688, 55 L. Ed. 2d 637, 98 S. Ct. 1355 (1978).As we have explained, the term "restraint of trade," as used in § 1, also "invokes the common law itself, and not merely the static content that the common law had assigned to the term in 1890." Business Electronics, 485 U.S.  at 732; see also GTE Sylvania, 433 U.S. at 53, n. 21; McNally v. United States, 483 U.S. 350, 372-373, 97 L. Ed. 2d 292, 107 S. Ct. 2875 (1987) (STEVENS, J., dissenting). Accordingly, this Court has reconsidered its decisions construing the Sherman Act when the theoretical underpinnings of those decisions are called into serious question. See, e.g., Copperweld Corp., supra, at 777; GTE Sylvania, supra, at 47-49; Tigner v. Texas, 310 U.S. 141, 147, 84 L. Ed. 1124, 60 S. Ct. 879 (1940).

但是,“遵循先例原则不是一个无法改变的命令”。在反垄断法领域,上诉法院的判决很好地揭示了这样一种冲突的利益,即承认和适应已经改变的环境与累积的经验教训之间的冲突。因此,考虑到人们普遍认为国会“希望法院通过吸收普通法的传统来明确《谢尔曼法》的广泛授权”,此时再推定应由国会来修订《谢尔曼法》是不合时宜的。正如我们所解释的那样,《谢尔曼法》第1条中所出现的“对贸易的限制”一词也“援引了普通法本身,而不仅仅是1890年制定该法时普通法所赋予该词的含义”。据此,当支撑解释《谢尔曼法》的判决的理论基础遭受质疑的时候,上诉法院就已经重新审议他们所作出的这些判决了。

Although we do not "lightly assume that the economic realities underlying earlier decisions have changed, or that earlier judicial perceptions of those realities were in error," we have noted that "different sorts of agreements" may amount to restraints of trade "in varying times and circumstances," and "it would make no sense to create out of the single term 'restraint of trade' a chronologically schizoid statute, in which a 'rule of reason' evolves with new circumstances and new wisdom, but a line of per se illegality remains forever fixed where it was." Business Electronics, supra, at 731-732.Just as Schwinn was "the subject of continuing controversy and confusion" under the "great weight" of scholarly criticism, GTE Sylvania, supra, at 47-48, Albrecht has been widely criticized since its inception. With the views underlying Albrecht eroded by this Court's precedent, there is not much of that decision to salvage. See, e.g., Neal v. United States, 516 U.S. 284, 295, 133 L. Ed. 2d 709, 116 S. Ct. 763 (1996); Patterson v. McLean Credit Union, 491 U.S. 164, 173, 105 L. Ed. 2d 132, 109 S. Ct. 2363 (1989); Rodriguez de Quijas v. Shearson/ American Express, Inc., 490 U.S. 477, 480-481, 104 L. Ed. 2d 526, 109 S. Ct. 1917 (1989).

尽管我们不会“轻易地假定早前判决所处的经济环境已经发生了变化,或者早前司法机关对当时经济环境的看法是错误的”,但是我们注意到“不同类型的协议”在“不同的情形下”会限制贸易,并且“根据‘贸易限制’这一单一术语去制定一部在时间上自相矛盾的成文法是毫无意义的,在这样的成文法中‘合理原则’随着新的形势和知识的出现而变化,但是本身违法原则却永远固定不变”。正如Schwinn案在学术批评的“重压”之下,一直“处于持续不断的争议与困惑中”,Albrecht 案从一开始就受到了广泛的批评。由于Albrecht 案最根本的观点已被上诉法院的先例所动摇,因此该案的判决已经没有多少借鉴价值了。

Although the rule of Albrecht has been in effect for some time, the inquiry we must undertake requires considering "'the effect of the antitrust laws upon vertical distributional restraints in the American economy today.'" GTE Sylvania, supra, at 53, n. 21 (quoting Schwinn, 388 U.S.  at 392 (Stewart, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part)). As the Court noted in ARCO, 495 U.S. at 336, n. 6, there has not been another case since Albrecht in which this Court has "confronted an unadulterated vertical, maximum-price-fixing arrangement." Now that we confront Albrecht directly, we find its conceptual foundations gravely weakened.


尽管Albrecht 案的判决已经生效一段时间了,但是要想解决我们的问题就必须思考“在今天的美国经济背景下,反垄断法对纵向分销限制的影响”。正如上诉法院在ARCO案中所注意到的那样,在Albrecht 案之后,上诉法院从未“遇到过不涉及纵向最高价格维持”的案件。我们直面Albrecht 案后认为该案的概念基础已经被严重削弱了。


(图片来源于网络)


In overruling Albrecht, we of course do not hold that all vertical maximum price fixing is per se lawful. Instead, vertical maximum price fixing, like the majority of commercial arrangements subject to the antitrust laws, should be evaluated under the rule of reason. In our view, rule-of-reason analysis will effectively identify those situations in which vertical maximum price fixing amounts to anticompetitive conduct.

当然,在推翻Albrecht 案时,我们并没有认为所有的纵向最高价格维持本身都是非法的。相反,和其他绝大部分受限于反垄断法的商业安排一样,我们应当根据合理原则审查最高价格维持。在我们看来,合理原则会让我们有效地识别最高价格维持是否构成反竞争行为。


There remains the question whether respondents are entitled to recover damages based on State Oil's conduct. Although the Court of Appeals noted that "the district judge was right to conclude that if the rule of reason is applicable, Khan loses," 93 F.3d at 1362, its consideration of this case was necessarily premised on Albrecht's per se rule. Under the circumstances, the matter should be reviewed by the Court of Appeals in the first instance. We therefore vacate the judgment of the Court of Appeals and remand the case for further proceedings consistent with this opinion.

尚存的一个问题是被上诉人是否有权依据国家石油公司的行为要求获得损害赔偿。尽管上诉法院注意到“地区法院的法官得出的结论是正确的,即如果合理原则得以适用,那么可汗公司会败诉”,但是这一结论必须以Albrecht 案的本身违法原则为前提。在这种情况下,该问题应当首先由上诉法院初审。因此,我们撤销了上诉法院的判决,并发回重审,以根据本意见进行进一步审理。

It is so ordered.


特此裁定。


译者注

向上滑动阅览

[1] 纵向价格限制(vertical maximum price fixing),又称转售价格维持,是指生产商或供应商在将产品出售给分销商或零售商时,对后者向第三人进行转售时的价格进行限制的情形。见黄勇,刘燕南:《关于我国反垄断法转售价格维持协议的法律适用问题研究》,载《社会科学》2013年第10期,第82页。译者注。

[2] 本身违法原则是指有些协议或做法因其本身对竞争存有不可弥补的危害性,故无需考虑其抗辩缘由而直接认定违法。见赵宸,奚庆:《美国最低转售价格维持规制路径研究——“本身违法”与“合理原则”之争》,载《价格理论与实践》2015年第4期,第31页。


[3] “合理原则”是指审案法院依当事人提供的证据,衡量限制竞争行为的好处和坏处,然后认定该行为合法还是违法。见王晓晔:《转售价格维持的反垄断规则适用“合理原则”之批判》,载《法商研究》2021年第1期,第41页。译者注。


[4] 根据Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc.一案中的定义,反垄断损害是指”injury of the type the antitrust laws were intended to prevent and that flows from that which makes defendants’ acts unlawful”.见James Murphy Dowd, 'Oligopsony Power: Antitrust Injury and Collusive Buyer Practices in Input Markets' (1996) 76 BU L Rev 1075.


[5] 这句话阐释了本身违法原则和合理原则之间的关系。法院只有在积累大量经验并且有足够的信息确信有关行为就算采用合理原则裁判也会得出违法结论后,方可适用本身违法原则。见赵宸,奚庆:《美国最低转售价格维持规制路径研究——“本身违法”与“合理原则”之争》,载《价格理论与实践》2015年第4期,第31-32页。译者注。


[6] 最低价格转售维持是上游厂商要求下游厂商的产品售价必须维持在某个特定价格的一种合约安排。见赵宸,奚庆:《美国最低转售价格维持规制路径研究——“本身违法”与“合理原则”之争》,载《价格理论与实践》2015年第4期,第31页。译者注。


[7] 纵向一体化是指企业以自行实施的方式获取本可借助市场交易得到的产品或服务,包括以自营方式进入新市场、纵向并购以及与上下游企业签订长期合同等多种方式。见[美]赫伯特·霍温坎普:《联邦反托拉斯政策:竞争法及其实践(第3版)》,徐光耀、江山等译,法律出版社2009年版,第411页。


[8] “品牌间竞争”是指限制经销商经销其他供应商的商品,而“品牌内竞争”则是指限制特定供应商产品的经销商与该产品的其他经销商就该等产品的转售进行竞争。见江山:《论纵向非价格限制的反垄断规制》,载《法律科学(西北政法大学学报)》2020年第1期,第133页。

微信扫码关注该文公众号作者

戳这里提交新闻线索和高质量文章给我们。
相关阅读
法律翻译|欧盟法院之“Schrems二号”判决:欧美《隐私盾协议》失效,标准合同条款仍然有效法律翻译 | 欧盟和美国就执法部门获取数据的谈判:分歧、挑战以及欧盟法律程序和选择(上)法律翻译 | 美国联邦第二巡回法院针对中美维C跨国反垄断诉讼的发回重审判决IPO财务造假经典案例汇编(8例)重磅!英国石油公司与阿布扎布石油公司联手合作,能源股上涨!法律翻译|《纽约大学法律评论》第97卷第5期经典案例:225111 Advertising specialist 广告专员法律翻译 | 《哈佛法律评论》第133卷第2期目录+摘要牛B大了!华人培训机构居然入选2023年芝大MBA的经典案例!书家俗词法律翻译 | 欧盟和美国就执法部门获取数据的谈判:分歧、挑战以及欧盟法律程序和选择(中)法律翻译 | 美国国家大学体育协会诉阿尔斯通案法律翻译|《纽大法律评论》第97卷第2期目录+摘要最新IPO被否原因及重点案例分析!(附138个经典案例)经典案例:公务员也能移民澳洲 |312111 Architectual draftsperson ‭‮筑建‬‬绘图员美国航空 (AA) 和捷蓝航空 (B6) 宣布在美国东北部战略合作【 更新:这个合作被判决违反反垄断法了】哈佛:From Financial Markets to ChatGPT法律翻译 | 布拉格登诉阿伯特案&萨顿诉美国联合航空公司案猫头鹰逃出动物园,自己在外面抓大老鼠吃不回来… 园方纠结再三:不抓了!最近发生一件民愤比较大的事,令我思考一些问题。双响炮经典案例,之前咨询了某些中介说两个提名不能同时申请,结果你猜怎么着?在拿到工业工程师后一周就收获了第二个ET的提名!拜登支持率升至42%,达去年6月以来最高!加州年度最佳教师 华女性侵儿童被捕!美法院批准扣押俄石油公司一飞机!加央行暂停加息进程闲话人生(233)一生最好的朋友郭进军法律翻译|理事会决议(欧盟)-《Interbus协定》议定书开放签署法律翻译|欧盟数据保护委员会 (EDPB) 发布最终版《数据主体权利指南——访问权》这一华人培训机构!入选2023年芝大MBA的经典案例!法律翻译|英国慈善机构慈善税收减免的限制法律翻译|美国蒙大拿州对TikTok实施全面禁令——蒙大拿州参议院419号法案高油价给石油公司带来暴利 壳牌CEO去年薪酬高达...法律翻译 | 欧盟和美国就执法部门获取数据的谈判:分歧、挑战以及欧盟法律程序和选择(下)法律翻译 |《纽大法律评论》第97卷第6期【定稿】法律翻译 | 美国国家大学体育协会诉阿尔斯通案经典案例:261313 Software ‭ engineer软件工程师|149311 Event Organizers活动策划一周回顾 | 市场监管总局发布四部反垄断法配套规章 瑞银集团收购瑞士信贷银行法律翻译 |《哈佛法律评论》第133卷第3期目录+摘要
logo
联系我们隐私协议©2024 redian.news
Redian新闻
Redian.news刊载任何文章,不代表同意其说法或描述,仅为提供更多信息,也不构成任何建议。文章信息的合法性及真实性由其作者负责,与Redian.news及其运营公司无关。欢迎投稿,如发现稿件侵权,或作者不愿在本网发表文章,请版权拥有者通知本网处理。